AOC: An economic ideology driven by Keynes, Marx, and ignorance

Updated: Feb 12


Over the weekend, we saw Representative Alexandria Ocasio Cortez profess her love for the economist Milton Keynes. (Wait, Milton Friedman, or John Keynes?) This is no surprise, of course. Most things the government does are under the ideology of "Keynesianism."



On today's podcast episode, we discussed AOC's love for terrible economic policies, and what we can do to convince her supporters otherwise. Listen HERE.



What's the ideology? Print money, Spend money. Tax, Print More, Spend More. Incentivize people to spend their money, not to save their money. The basic idea is that consumption is the main driver behind an economy. More consumption equals more growth. So on, and so forth.


You might have read something that you agreed with in that last paragraph. The idea that "consumption spurs growth" is ingrained in our minds as early as we can all remember. Before you remain sold on that ideology, remember, this is AOC's favorite economist..


The problems I see are:


  1. Where is the money for the consumption coming from?

  2. Who is spending it?

  3. Could that money have been saved or invested in a more efficient way?


In AOC's mind, both of those should be answered with "The All-powerful US Government!"


Of course, we know that the Government is an inefficient and bloated mess. Money taken through taxation, or through money printing, is rarely spent wisely, and that matters.


True economic growth comes from savings, not consumption. When people save and invest, the money that spurs from this practice is rooted in real value, not just in Federal Reserve Notes. The more that is saved in an economy, the more capital there will be available for economic investment in other sectors. Without this store of capital, the "investment" must come from Fiat money. If the investment comes through Fiat money, it has no real value, and it devalues the rest of the money in circulation.


If the investment comes from taxation, then the money is spent more inefficiently than it otherwise would have been. $50,000 that could have been saved and made available for investment in production, is instead used for a single toilet seat, paid for by the Department of Defense.



We talked about this on today's podcast episode, which you can listen to at the top of the website, or find on your podcast app. Tune in every day for a new episode about today's news and politics, from a Liberty-minded perspective.


The following is an article originally posted by FEE.org, and written by Richard M. Ebeling. It has been reprinted with permission.


John Maynard Keynes: The Damage Still Done by a Defunct Economist


Keynes Provided a Rationale for Government Spending and Pandering to Special Interests


Seventy years ago, on February 4, 1936, the English economist John Maynard Keynes (1883–1946) published what soon became his most famous work, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. Few books, in so short a time, have gained such wide influence and generated so destructive an impact on public policy. What Keynes succeeded in doing was to provide a rationale for what governments always like to do: spend money and pander to special interests.


In the process Keynes helped undermine what had been three of the essential institutional ingredients of a free-market economy: the gold standard, balanced gov­ernment budgets, and open competitive markets. In their place Keynes’s legacy has given us paper-money inflation, government deficit spending, and more politi­cal intervention throughout the market.


It would, of course, be an exaggeration to claim that without Keynes and the Keynesian revolution inflation, deficit spending, and interventionism would not have occurred. For decades before the appearance of Keynes’s book, the political and ideological climate had been shifting toward ever-greater government involvement in social and economic affairs, due to the growing influ­ence of collectivist ideas among intellectuals and policy-makers.


But before the appearance of The General Theory, many of the advocates of such collectivist policies had to get around the main body of economic thinking which still argued that in general the best course was for gov­ernment to keep its hands off the market, maintain a sta­ble currency backed by gold, and restrain its own taxing and spending policies.


The classical economists of the eighteenth and nine­teenth centuries had persuasively demonstrated that government intervention prevented the smooth func­tioning of the market. They constructed a body of eco­nomic theory which clearly showed that governments have neither the knowledge nor the ability to direct economic affairs. Freedom and prosperity are best assured when government is, in general, limited to pro­tecting people’s lives and property, with the competitive forces of supply and demand bringing about the neces­sary incentives and coordination of people’s activities.


During the Napoleonic wars of the early nineteenth century, many European countries experienced serious inflations as governments resorted to the printing press to fund their war expenditures. The lesson the classical economists learned was that the hand of the government had to be removed from the handle of that printing press if monetary stability was to be maintained. The best way of doing this was to link a nation’s currency to a com­modity like gold, require banks to redeem their notes for gold on demand at a fixed rate of exchange, and limit any increases in the amount of such bank notes in cir­culation to additional deposits of gold left in the banks by their depositors.


They also concluded that deficit spending was a dan­gerous means of funding government programs. It enabled governments to create the illusion that they could spend without imposing a cost on society in the form of higher taxes; they could borrow and spend today, and defer the tax cost until some tomorrow when the loans would have to be repaid. The classical econo­mists called for annually balanced budgets, enabling the electorate to see more clearly the cost of government spending. If a national emergency, such as a war, were to force the government to borrow, then when the crisis passed, the government should run budget surpluses to pay off the debt.


These were considered the tried and true policies for a healthy society. And these were the policies that Keynes did his best to try to overthrow in the pages of The General Theory. He argued that a market economy was inherently unstable, open to swings of irrational investor optimism and pessimism, which resulted in unpredictable and wide fluctuations in output, employ­ment, and prices. Only government, he believed, could take the long view and rationally keep the economy on an even keel by running deficits to stimulate the econ­omy during depressions and surpluses to rein it in dur­ing inflationary booms. He therefore attacked the notion of annual balanced budgets; instead, government should balance its budget over the “business cycle.”


To do this job, Keynes said, governments could not be hamstrung by the “barbarous relic” of the gold stan­dard. Wise politicians, guided by brilliant economists like himself, had to have the flexibility to increase the money supply, manipulate interest rates, and change the foreign-exchange rates at which currencies traded for each other. They required this power so they could gen­erate any amount of spending needed to put people back to work through public-works projects and gov­ernment-stimulated private investments. Limiting increases in the money supply to the quantity of gold would only get in the way, Keynes insisted.


Keynes believed not only that the market economy could not keep itself on an even keel, he also believed that it would be undesirable to allow the market to work. He once said that to have the market determine prices and wages to balance supply and demand was to submit society to a cruel and unjust “economic jugger­naut.” Instead, he wanted wages and prices to be politi­cally fixed on the basis of “what is ‘fair’ and ‘reasonable’ as between the [social] classes.”


The level of wages imposed by trade unions, for example, was to be viewed as sacrosanct, even if many workers were priced out of the market because the level was higher than potential employers thought those workers were worth. The government, instead, was to print money, run deficits, and push up prices to any level needed to make it again profitable for employers to hire workers. In other words, perpetual price inflation was to be the means to assure “full employment” in the face of aggressive trade unions.


No Check on Spending

In addition, when the balanced-budget rule was over­thrown there was no longer any check on govern­ment spending. As James M. Buchanan and Richard E. Wagner pointed out in Democracy in Deficit (1977), once government is freed from the restraint of making tax­payers directly and immediately pay for what it spends, every conceivable special-interest group can appeal to the politicians to feed their wants. The politicians, desir­ing votes and campaign contributions, happily offer to satisfy the gluttony of favored groups. At the same time, the taxpayers easily fall prey to the delusion that gov­ernment can give something for nothing to virtually everyone at no cost to them.


Indeed, politicians can now play the game of offer­ing more and more dollars to special interests, while lowering taxes. The government simply fills the gap by borrowing, imposing a greater debt burden on future generations. Either taxes will have to go up in the years ahead or the government will turn to the printing press to pay what it owes, all the while claiming that it’s being done to generate “national prosperity” and fund the “socially necessary” programs of the welfare state.


In one of the most famous passages in The General Theory, Keynes said that “the ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is com­monly understood. Indeed the world is ruled by little else. Practical men, who believe themselves to be exempt from any intellectual influences, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist. Madmen in authori­ty, who hear voices in the air, are distilling their frenzy from some academic scribbler of a few years back.”


Seventy years after the appearance of The General Theory, many practical men of affairs and politicians in authority remain the slaves of defunct economists and academic scribblers. The tragedy for our times is that among the voices they still hear in the air as they cor­ruptly mismanage everything they touch is that of John Maynard Keynes.

Listen to the Podcast!

© 2019 Good Morning Liberty 

Created by Paradexo

  • Facebook
  • Twitter
  • YouTube
  • Instagram
  • TikTok

Nashville, TN

email: nate@goodmorningliberty.us